In 1954, Harry Markowitz was a graduate student in economics at the University of Chicago and had just finished defending his thesis. Most of the committee accepted his work. But Milton Friedman, an economist with a national reputation, and easily the most influential member of the economics faculty, had a problem. While he found no errors in Markowitz’s work, the problem was that it contained no economics. Markowitz’s thesis was about investments, and in Friedman’s view, that wasn’t economics.
In the end, the department did grant Markowitz his Ph.D. But Friedman had raised an interesting question: What exactly is finance? Is it a science like biology or chemistry? Or is it more like sociology or psychology? Or is it something else?
In 2013, the committee that awards the Nobel prize in economics offered one clue. In that year, one prize went to Eugene Fama, an academic who had pioneered what is now known as the Efficient Markets Hypothesis. Fama’s theory argues that investors are rational and that they act with mathematical rigor and discipline when they buy and sell investments.
But at the same time, the Nobel committee also awarded a prize in economics to another academic, Robert Shiller, who holds the opposite view. In Shiller’s work, he’s found that investors are only sometimes rational and that psychology is a significant—if not the most significant—factor motivating investor behavior.
That, of course, doesn’t offer a very satisfying conclusion. The Nobel committee seemed to be saying that investing might be a rigorous science—or it might not be. But they really weren’t sure, and they didn’t say. Perhaps what they were trying to communicate is that both views are partly correct. Fama is right that sometimes investors approach things scientifically. But Shiller is also right in observing that investors lose their heads sometimes. In general, that’s the way I see it. Investors can be rational, but they can also be quite irrational.
In the decades since Markowitz’s initial work, researchers have helped to more clearly delineate the aspects of finance that are scientific from those that are more subjective. The trouble, though, is that it can be tough to know which is which. And oftentimes that gives rise to disagreements among partisans within personal finance. One camp will view a particular question as purely scientific—with a right and a wrong answer—while the other will view it as entirely subjective and open to debate.
When debates like this arise, the two camps rarely see eye to eye. Those who view a question as having a right and a wrong answer can’t comprehend why anyone would persist in debating it—like continuing to debate whether the Earth is round. On the other hand, those who see a question as subject to debate are endlessly frustrated by the dogmatic stubbornness of those who believe there is only one answer.
This dynamic poses a problem for investors. As Mark Twain purportedly once said, “It ain’t what you don’t know that gets you into trouble. It’s what you know for sure that just ain’t so.” Over the years, I’ve come across many such debates. Below are the ones that, in my experience, seem to cause the most consternation. On each of these questions, people tend to become overly dogmatic. In my view, though, each is an open question and should be subject to discussion:
Should you bet on cryptocurrency? In the past, I’ve described my concerns about bitcoin. In short, I don’t like it because it lacks measurable intrinsic value. For that reason, I don’t recommend it. Others, however, point out that the dollar itself has no intrinsic value. It only has value because we all agree it has value. Crypto enthusiasts believe that one or more digital currencies may one day attain that same status. And while the U.S. government has the ability to create new dollars, which can generate inflation—as we’re now witnessing—bitcoin, by design, is capped. No more can be created. This debate has gone round and round for years. So far, I’m not convinced on cryptocurrencies, but this is a case in which I don’t think anyone should say there is a “right” and a “wrong” answer. Like a lot of new things, it bears watching.
When should you claim Social Security? If you’re eligible for Social Security, you can claim it as early as 62 years old or as late as 70. And, with only a few exceptions, the benefit increases by about 8% for each year that you wait. For that reason, many believe that the best strategy is to wait as long as possible to maximize the benefit. That’s my view. But I’ve also seen people develop detailed analyses to argue that claiming earlier makes more sense and that it can be a waste to forgo multiple years of benefits. This camp believes that benefits should be claimed early so that those dollars can be invested in the stock market, where they would likely earn a higher return. This is another argument which seems to have no end. There are, of course, too many unknowns—including your own longevity and market returns—to be too wedded to any one strategy. There’s no right or wrong on this.
Should you pay down your mortgage? If you have extra funds, should you make extra mortgage payments, or even pay off your balance entirely? This debate is similar in spirit to the Social Security question. The strictly mathematical view is that it doesn’t make sense to pay off a mortgage with a historically low rate of 2% or 3% when those funds could be invested in the stock market to earn 8% or 10%. There’s a good amount of logic to this argument because the stock market does go up, on average. The U.S. market has historically delivered a positive return almost 75% of the time, on an annual basis. But as we’ve seen so far this year, it doesn’t always go up. So it’s hardly guaranteed that an investor will earn more by investing than by making extra mortgage payments. And further, this strictly mathematical approach ignores certain realities, including the satisfaction of being debt-free. So there’s no right or wrong on this question either.
Is 4% still a safe portfolio withdrawal rate in retirement? In 1994, a financial planner named Bill Bengen concluded that 4% is the safest portfolio withdrawal rate for retirees. And in short order, this became known as the “4% rule.” But as Bengen himself noted, this 4% conclusion was based on a number of assumptions and, therefore, not universally applicable. In his own practice, in fact, Bengen said he preferred 4.5%. The bottom line: There’s no reason 4% should be treated as a rule. Still, there are many who regard it as such. On the other side, though, there are now those who believe that 4% is an outdated figure and that it would be borderline reckless to build a plan around that number. Over the years, the research on withdrawal rates has been extended and refined, and it’s certainly worth following. But since every retiree is different and will live through different market conditions, I wouldn’t be too swayed by the dogma on either side of this debate.